Sociologidagarna
i Stockholm 15-17 mars 2012. Lördag 17 mars pass 1, klockan 9:30-10:40.
”Hur att teoretisera”. Moderator:
Richard Swedberg. @The author.
In modern scientific articles and monographs one presents only
results. In earlier scholarly writings that took the form of more paradigmatic
essays it was customary to include also the trials and tribulations that
preceded the emergence of the results. I will here try to pick up the
old-fashioned path and describe an intellectual process that began in 1950 with
the writing of my MA-thesis, A Semantic
Role Theory, at the University of Minnesota
The adjective "many-splendored" describes a society
with personal freedom and a sparkling differentiation of six self-governing
realms: economy, politics, science, art, religion, and morality. When these societal
realms are integrated, so that no one realm rules over any of the others, we
have, in my view, a good society.
The Many-Splendored
Society is not a typical collection of essays of theoretical relevance,
more or less revised and integrated, as are works of Max Weber (1920, 1921),
Robert K Merton (1957), Herbert Blumer (1969),
Clifford Geertz (1973), Edward Shils (1982), all of
which have greatly inspired me. The
Many-Splendored Society certainly has material from my older essays but it
is reworked into a whole cloth and everything is presented in English. Actually,
my native tongue, Swedish, is not well suited to the topic at hand since the
people and intellectuals who speak Swedish use the same word, "samhället," for both state and society, an anathema of
being many-splendored.
"A classic must stand at
last alone: without apology, exegesis, or alibi. It must speak for itself to
strangers; it must be intelligible, and seem true, after all its special
friends are dead. It must have the minimum of weakness, vagueness, vanity,
wind. It must be well made at the seams, to stand the long voyage it hopes to
make, and to endure the waves either of contempt or of competition. It must
have been made, in other words, by one who knew how to make such things, and nothing
else about him will matter: who he was, how he looked, or what he thought about
other things than the things he treated"
In the social
sciences, particularly sociology, the classic texts are still alive. We cannot
learn sociology simply by reading the most recent textbook. Above all, to
theorize in sociology you must attend to its classics. As you have seen from
the program, most papers in the workgroup on theory are explorations of
classical texts. Actually we have good reasons to return all the way to Aristotle
when we study social science,
particularly if the topic is politics, aesthetics, or ethics.
No modern physicist or biologist have such reasons to return
to any writer from antiquity. But we social scientists do. I do not think this
means that social science is backwards compared to natural science. Social
science is the easier one of the two. The grammar
of social reality is easier than the mathematics
of physical reality, and the grammar is known almost automatically by any
language brain. Already in ancient Athens one could acquire abundant and
accurate knowledge of human affairs; the wisdom of its dramatists and philosophers
has produced centuries of aha-experiences. It was harder for the Athenians to
learn about phenomena of physical and biological reality. Such knowledge
required more conscious initiatives and technologically advanced instruments.
Let me assure you that it is wonderful to live a life in
communication with the classics, the brightest of the ages. In my darker moments
in USA, England, Sweden, and Spain, it has been a consolation to be able to
turn to the classics.
Let me say a word about the Great Books movement.
After World War II,
educational systems in many countries favored early specialization. That which
had formerly been called studium generale,, “general studies,” and which preceded occupationally
geared studies, was accordingly cut back.
A heroic attempt to
re-establish general studies with a new (or rediscovered) pedagogy was made
after the War at the University of Chicago, a private university. Its studium generalewas a
set of courses in certain subjects, all having a tradition of basic research.
In small, compulsory seminars, all freshmen read, discussed, and analyzed the
most important original works in philosophy, physics, history, and social studies.
The aim was not that the students should learn about the entire series of
“Great Books” chosen by Robert Maynard Hutchins and Mortimer Adler. Most of the 54 books were works in Western
humanism from Homer
to
William James in their
original (but if necessary translated) versions. Some original scientific texts
were also included by Aristotle, Newton, HuygensLavoisier
ourierFaraday, Darwin, Marx, and Freud. Rather, the goal of the seminars was to
develop critical thinking, not only through exchanges with fellow students and
teachers, but also with the pre-eminent thinkers of the Western world.
Different and
sometimes watered-down versions of the Chicago model of “Great books coursessoon came to Columbia, Harvard, Yale, and Brown, and to other colleges
and universitiesin the United States with ambitious
undergraduate programs. Most of these programs have been met with declining
interest, and have waned in importance. They have suffered from some students’
desires to choose easier courses, and their contents became subject to
criticism by feminists and multiculturalists as an
ultimate bias and celebration of Western white males.
When I was teaching at
the Graduate School of Columbia University for twelve years in the 50s and 60s,
the undergraduates in Columbia College had a mandatory Great Books Course. In
the graduate Department of Sociology we agreed that I would give a seminar of
great sociological classics. We would read a different book (or sometimes a
longer book section) each week for twelve weeks. No free-riding allowed. If
someone had been unable to do the home work, they were allowed to stay in the
seminar, but with some restrictions on participating in the discussion. One
seminar member had the responsibility to introduce the book of the week, and later
in the report also include chosen points of the group discussion. Some names
recurred most every year -- de Tocqueville, Marx, Weber, Simmel, Durkheim, Mead -- while I varied others from year to year. Needless to
say I got myself the good education that my colleagues thought I already had
when they assigned the seminar to me.
Unfortunately, Richard
Swedberg was a teenager when this took place. His
idea to replace the teaching of theory
with the teaching of theorizing did
not occur to me. I remember that some of Lazarsfeld’s
doctoral students in my classics seminar raised issues of the methodology of
theorizing. Merton’s students, like my own, were mostly interested in the
substantive theory of the classics. The Department itself was convinced that if
we could teach superior methodology and superior theory, any of our students
could then take up specialties such as race, crime, family, etc. on her or his
own; there was no need for our curriculum to cover everything called sociology.
Classics often inspire a life in scholarship. To get to know
a classic of your choice may help your career as a scholar.
Let me cite from the first words I read by Max Weber. They
came from a lecture at Munich University on “Wissenschaft
als Beruf” given in 1917 at
the request of the students, many of whom planned a career in science. Here is
Weber’s original German text and a translation from the 1940s into English by
Professor Hans Gerth of University of Wisconsin and
C. Wright Mills, his graduate student:
One or two sentences in this quote are typically Weber, i.e.
like gothic castles with many towers. My mother tongue is Swedish; the first foreign
language I learned in school was German, later came French and English, and I
had had only one year at an English-speaking university when I began reading
Max Weber in America. I shall not hide the fact that, even in C. Wright Millssmoothening English editing, I had to struggle
with the above passage when I first encountered it in 1950 as a graduate
student at the University of Minnesota. However, in due course, and when I
discovered also the original German, these pages of text reinforced what was to
me a very moving and also a molding passage.
There are many bottoms in Weber’s statement about a career in
science, particularly social science. The quote has a message about the necessity,
but academically unrewarding efforts, of a sociologist (acting in the role of
general social scientist) to cross into the specialties of others, i.e. what
Richard Swedberg and Patrik
Aspers and some others who are here today do in their
major works. Have solace in Weber’s remark!
The next message in Weber’s sermon is that the work of a scientist
must, nevertheless, be highly specialized to achieve enduring results. Scientists are
normally judged (and promoted) on the basis of discoveries in a narrow field.
To reach fame in the very short life-time that is given us, a scientist must persist in a specialty until a discovery
is established.
Weber preaches, furthermore, that scientific endeavors depend
on passion, not just rationality. The
genuine pursuit of science includes a passion for discovery. However, errors in
using the scientific methods can never be excused by the fact that the author
was passionate.
Moreover, there is a serious warning that your entire worth,
“the fate of your soul,” depends on doing scientific discoveries correctly. Thus, your conformity to, or
deviation from, the norms of the scientific methods shapes the evaluation you
will receive from your encounters in the community of science. Clearly, for a
scientist there is no substitute for correct comparisons and experiments, for
accuracy of measurements, for carefulness in use of sources and statistics, for
truthfulness in tales and modeling. Here, the very meaning of your short life
on this earth is at stake, when “thousands of years must pass before you enter
into life and thousands more wait in silence.”
Finally, your own development to a mature, autonomous self,
to a personality of your own, depends on making your chosen science into, not
just a daily routine, but into your calling (Beruf).
My generation of Swedish students of sociology had not had Max
Weber on their reading lists, except perhaps docent Bertil
Pfannenstill’s students in Lund. Max Weber eventually
became my sociological house god.
Like Marx, Weber came to most Swedish sociologists from America,
and, interestingly enough, he came in full attention only after Marx had become the main macro-sociologist of academic choice
among Swedish sociologists. We were a few who became Weberians.
In the 1970s, Kerstin Lindskoug
The greatest help for anyone interested in following us on
the Weberian route is Richard Swedberg’s
The Max Weber Dictionary. Key Words and Central Concepts
There was a time when I attended high school in the 1940s in
Sweden when I wanted to become a chemist; I attended what the Germans call Realgymnasium, i.e. one that specialized in the natural sciences. When friends and
relatives wondered: "What do you want to do with chemistry?" I could
answer by telling them about “the periodic system.” This was a classification
of all the elements in a table where columns and lines pointed to common
characteristics of the elements. In 1869 Dimitri I Mendelévy had created a first version of chemistry's
periodic system by classifying the elements, seven to a column, according to
their atomic weight.
My excellent chemistry teacher made it clear that although
there are about 100 elements, they can form over a million combinations. If you
know where in the periodic table an element is located you have already got a great
deal of information about its characteristics and its ability to unite with
other elements. Blanks in the table meant that the elements had not yet been
discovered. This was a lot for a budding chemist to work on, and perhaps a
chance to discover something new!
When I became a social scientist I often missed the elegance
of chemistry's periodic system, especially when confronted with the question
"What constitutes a modern society?" I was forced to ponder this question
on many occasions. For half a century I have had opportunities to study modern
society as a sociology teacher and scholar, as a publisher of social science
books, as a pollster with involvement in market, media, and value research, as
a consultant to businesses, voluntary associations, and museums, as an
ideologue for a political party, and as a newspaper editor and columnist. Nowhere
did I find a classification for this study as elegant as that to be found in
the periodic system of chemistry of my school days.
In volume 2 of my current work in 7 volumes called The Many-Splendored Society I have
proposed a Periodic Table of Social Reality.
A |
Societal |
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
|
B |
Critical |
Executive
descriptions |
Executive
evaluations |
Executive
prescriptions |
Emotive |
Emotive |
Emotive
pre- |
|
C |
Lifestyles |
Learning
buffs |
Money-centered |
Civic- minded |
Aesthetes |
Believers |
Compassionate |
|
D |
Cardinal |
Knowledge |
Wealth |
Order |
Beauty
|
Sacredness |
Virtue |
|
E |
Stratification |
Competence |
Class |
Power |
Taste |
Piety |
Rectitude |
|
F |
Reward |
Priority
of findings |
Monetary
devices |
Positions, |
Artistic
fame |
Reverence |
Testimonials |
|
G |
Rationality |
Scientific
method |
Market |
Democracy |
Aesthetics |
Theology |
Ethics |
|
H |
Freedom |
Academic |
Free |
Civic |
Artistic
license |
Religious
freedom |
Freedom
of conscience |
|
I |
Spontaneous
order |
Self- |
Market |
Public |
Art
improvisations |
Non-ritual
prayers |
Unplanned
civilities |
|
J |
Organ- |
Academies |
Firms |
Public
admini- |
Theatres,
museums, etc |
Temples |
Welfare
organizations |
|
K |
Networks |
Learned |
Markets |
Electorates |
Bohemia |
Sects |
Good |
|
L |
Mass |
Science
|
Advertising
media |
Tribunes |
Stages,
novels, exhibits, etc |
Holy
texts, cults |
Heralds |
|
M |
Netorgs |
Competing
laboratories |
B2B |
Political |
Schools
(=approaches to art) |
Rival
congregations |
Contending
moral groups |
|
N |
Makers |
Scholars |
Entrepreneurs |
Legislators |
Creative
artists |
Prophets |
Sources
of high norms |
|
O |
Keepers |
Librarians |
(Central) |
Judges |
Critics |
Learned
Clerics |
Ethicists |
|
P |
Brokers |
Teachers |
Salesmen |
Bureaucrats |
Performers,
entertainers |
Preachers |
Moralists
Carers |
|
Q |
Takers |
Students |
Consumers |
Citizens |
Fans
of culture |
Congregation
adherents |
Decent
people |
|
R |
Providers |
Consultants |
Outside
investors |
Legal |
Patrons |
Chaplains
to other realms |
Ethics
|
|
S |
Procurers |
Research |
Deposit
taking |
Taxmen |
Supplicants |
Salvation
seekers |
Moral |
|
Please note that The Periodic Table deals with social
reality, i.e. what is given and constructed by man’s unique environment of
symbols. Other aspects of human living belong in another table.
A closer look at symbolic environments of societies allows
us to specify communicative actions (Row B) as evaluations, or prescriptions,
or descriptions. Such communications are either executive – map out the world
around us, evaluate it, and manage it – or they are emotive – add and shape
emotions to events in our outer or inner world. The six kinds of communicative
acts are thus: executive descriptions (Column 1), executive evaluations (Column
2), executive prescriptions (Column 3); emotive descriptions (Column 4),
emotive evaluations (Column 5), emotive prescriptions (Column 6). These are
purely communications by symbols.
Science (Row B, Column 1) is connected with an overrepresentation
of executive descriptions, for example, facts and generalizations. Economy and
business (Row B, Column 2) are connected with executive evaluations, for
example, prices and costs. Politics and administration (Row B, Column 3) are
connected with executive prescriptions, for example, laws and regulations. Art
(Row B, Column 4) in all its forms deals with descriptive visions that are emotive,
expressive. Religions (Row B, Column 5) relate to expressive evaluations, for
example, ideas about the fundamental value of mankind and the meaning of life.
Morality (Row B, Column 6) contains expressive prescriptions, ethical rules of
conduct. Thus, the six communicative acts provide a potential for six
fundamental realms of life in human society: economy, polity, science,
religion, morality, and art.
In these realms of society, important products are created
which we refer to as their cardinal values (Row D). They are wealth in the economy,
order in the body politic, knowledge in science, sacredness in religion, virtue
in the realm of morality, and beauty in the sphere of art.
When the societal realms hold each other in balance so that
no one rules over the other, and when each one can freely export and import
their respective cardinal values, then, and only then, do we have a
many-splendored society.
Each realm has its own pattern of ranking, its
stratification (Row E): competence in science, class (purchasing clout) in the
economy, power in the body politic, taste in art, rectitude in morality, and piety
in the realm of religion.
Reward systems (Row F) also differ between the realms. Each
realm has its own way of expressing awe, admiration, and deference. In science
the greatest testimonials are awarded to those who are the first to make and
publish a discovery. In economy, deference is paid to money and the display of
spectacular investments and consumption. In the body politic, deference to the
powerful is expressed in the form of titles and public tributes. In art and
entertainment, one achieves artistic fame. In religion, deference is shown in
reverence, and in the realm of morality, it is expressed in the real brick of
personal respect.
Societal realms are, more or less, rationally organized.
However, each may develop its own type of rationality (Row G). In the contemporary
institutions of knowledge, the most common rationality is the scientific
method; in the economy the presently dominant type of rationality at the time
of this writing is the market economy; in the body politic the modern rationality
is that of democracy on the domestic scene, and diplomacy on the international
scene.
Each realm also has its special type of freedom (Row H): academic
freedom, free trade, civil rights, artistic license, freedom of faith, and
freedom of conscience. Freedom is implemented in a society, not as an abstract
philosophical proclamation; it must be anchored in the routines of the
respective realms.
Each realm contains four recurrent structures. First, there
are organizations (Row J), such as state agencies, firms, research institutes,
churches, theatres, et cetera. Second, outside such formal organizations, we
find networks (Row K), such as electorates, markets, grids of volunteers,
colleagues, supporters, et cetera. Third, we note that each realm also has its
media (Row L). In the printed media there are specialized publications, or
specialized pages featuring politics, economy, science, art, religion, and the
ethics of interpersonal relations. Fourth, we take special note of a
combination of a full-fledged network as the environment of full-fledged
organizations. These, “netorgs” (Row M) seem to have greater effects on societies
than any other structures.
Wealth is created by entrepreneurial producers, recorded by
accountants, and preserved by insurers and bankers in financial institutions,
conveyed by trading distributors, and possibly distributed to consumers. The
political order is formulated by leaders and legislators, preserved by the
judiciary, the police, and the military, and is implemented by technocrats and
bureaucrats, and received by the subjects or citizens. Knowledge is created by
scientists and learned men and women, is preserved by libraries, is
communicated by teachers, and is received by students. Sacredness in religions
is created by prophets, preserved by those versed in the Holy Scriptures and
rites, conveyed by the clergy, and are received by congregations. Beauty in art
is created by artists, is preserved on stages and in collections open to the
public, is conveyed by interpreting artists, guides and critics, and is
received by the public. Thus, each realm has four recurrent internal functions.
They stand for the creation (Row N) or preservation (Row O) or distribution
(Row P) or reception (Row Q) of the cardinal values that are produced in the different
life spheres.
The relative autonomy of the categories in The Table of Societal
Realms is more than an impetus to provide the categories with separate names,
and is also more than an impetus for individuals to specialize in one sphere
rather than being a jack of all trades. The relative autonomy signals a
confederative nature of a society's parts. Every realm always embeds some
“alien” elements from other life spheres, and needs these elements. The cells
in our Table of Societal Realms are islands, but they are not alone and are
never entirely to themselves. In Row R and S we have provided space for the individuals
who are responsible for essential exchanges between realms, the Providers and
the Procurers. A society does not have to create high walls between its realms.
The sum total of these differentiations is what we have
called “the many-splendored society.” Its lifestyles (Row C) hint at the varied
options an individual in such a society may enjoy in everyday life.
I was fortunate to have as my first teacher of sociology Torgny T. Segerstedt, a Swede who
had been a professor of philosophy. His intellectual roots were in the Scottish
Enlightenment; his main interest was the study of the role of language in
society. His first book was called Verklighet och värde
There is an enormous secondary literature about Mead and de
Saussure. Both these pioneering books were edited by their students from
lecture notes, and they were not particularly easy reading. I decided to check
also some writings by their editors. How had the editors handled and elaborated
the heritage of their great masters? This turned out to be a stroke of luck.
Meads editor, and author of the long introduction, was
Charles W Morris, a semiotician and a philosopher in
the American pragmatic tradition. In his 1946 book, Signs, Language and Behavior, he divided the actual use of language
into a universal classification. "These usages may be called in order the informative, the valuative, the incitive, and the
systemic uses of signs. These are the
most general sign usages; other usages are subdivisions and specializations of
these four."
de Saussure's editor and
collaborator was Charles Bally and in his book La langage et la vie from 1913 I found a
wonderful comment on the meanings of the phrase "It is raining"
“If we make some slight
changes in his illustrations we can put the phrase into all Morris’ categories.
It may, for instance, stand for:
It has now started to rain
(informative)
The weather is bad (valuative)
Shut the window! (incitive)”
Bally made it clear that the language of social reality had
a grammar, but it was not the school grammar. The meaning of its symbols was modified
by the social situation in which language was used. The social grammar is not
the same as the school grammar! There is a special “understanding principle” in
the social language.
Here then emerged the Tri-section of language that became so
fundamental in theory of The Many-Splendored Society. But I changed the
terminology into descriptions, evaluations,
and prescriptions.
I have no recollection of the background of my systematic
use of a Bi-section of communication, its instrumental and expressive forms. It
seems that I started using it as a self-evident: a duality between head and
heart, or between skill and emotion.
Charles Stevenson, an American philosopher of the same period
as Charles W. Morris and in the same tradition of pragmatism, (1944), clarified
this attribute of language by penetrating its emotive component. When we say
with Shakespeare that "All the world's a
stage" this emotive description is distinct, Stevenson argues, from an
executive description such as "There is a routine in real life, each man
going through a prearranged course"; or, "There is a good deal of
trivial make-believe in each man's conduct." When the very words rather then what they stand for convey emotions -- such as
"Long live the King" -- Stevenson talks about their “independent
emotive meaning.”
Charles Stevenson’s best student in sociology was Ulf Himmelstrand
Eventually I began to express a dichotomy, a Bi-section, in
terms of “executive actions,” e.g., issuing instructions, giving a scientific
lecture, driving a car, getting dressed for a football game, as opposed to “emotive
actions” e.g., applauding a team's victory in a football game, reading romantic
poetry, hand-wringing.
In Paris, the sophisticated axiomatic
theory of signs and symbols of Greimas
Proposition 5:2 recalled. Tri- and Bisections of Language Usages and
The Understanding Principle: a) Any symbolic
environment tends to become differentiated by the language brain into a
trisection of descriptive, evaluative, and prescriptive usages, each of which
contains a bisection of executive and emotive components, i.e. totally six
types of usages. (b) The language brain of persons in this symbolic environment
has the capacity to differentiate these six usages regardless of
their syntax.
Together the Tri- and Bi-section of language turned out to
be fundamental in the discourses that create economy, politics, science, art,
religion, and morality. Torgny Segerstedt
These starting points of social inquiry are found in line B
of the Periodic Table of Social Reality above.
My early backups to my budding periodic system were books
and statistics designed to be comprehensive descriptions, not theory.
Which subjects ought to be found in a library that best describe
modern society? This was our chief concern when I and other social scientists
together with a senior librarian, Carl White, were to list and classify the
most important books in the social sciences that were to form part of the base
of a new college library
Many new colleges were founded in the 1960s and they needed
libraries with top selection.
I classified the categories of sociology books basic to a
new college library in this way
Precursors
of Systematic Sociology
Works that Made History
The Present State of Sociology
Theoretical Sociology
Social Psychology
Groups and Encounters
Organizations
Markets
Social Stratification
Institutional Realms
Topics of Sociology
Human and Non-human Resources
Family Sociology
Economic sociology
Political Sociology
Sociology of Science and Education
Sociology of Art
Sociology of Religion
Urban and Rural Life, Communities and
Societies
Social Problems
Methods of Sociology
Under these headings I proposed a
total of 210 book titles in sociology as a minimum for a new library for any
college or for ambitious junior colleges. To this a list was added a selection
of journals by the project director.
The statistical backup of my budding periodic system was
also in the form of a book project.
What is important to learn from statistics describing a contemporary
society? Which ones are the basic 100 tables? This was the main problem of the
editors of A Sociological Almanac for The
United States
One should not pretend that there is agreement among social
scientists as to the most relevant information that enters into a routine description
of a society. However, as a rule, social scientists and historians, in dealing
with total societies, begin by discussing:
1. Human resources
2. Material resources
Then they may process along many paths, but in the end they
have usually described six interrelated but different realms of society. The
latter are:
3. Polity
6. Religion
4. Economy 7. Art
5. Science
8. Ethics
The Preface told that the tables of this almanac are
numbered according to the above scheme. Thus, any table with a prefix ‘6’ will
deal with religion, any table with the prefix ‘4’ will deal with the economy,
etc. The same holds for the subheadings of the text (pp. 31-32). The Almanac
had 54 pages of tables. The Almanac
also included a guide “How to read a table” by Murray Gendell
(p 33-35) which enhanced its use as a supplementary text in undergraduate
course about the U.S. society.
At this time, I can say that behind the categories of books
and statistics list hides bits and pieces of a widely used Exposition of Categories
for social sciences, a Kategorielehre,
provided by the young Max Weber
My book Social Theory
and Social Practice, published the same year, 1962, as the learned society
whose 50th jubilee we celebrate at today’s meeting, linked the above
classifications of books and statistics to the categories of the periodic
system of social reality. When I first published them in support of theory I
was still so uncertain about them that I buried them in footnotes
No author, dead or alive, is a supreme lord over his or her
own formulations. New generations create own formulations. As George Herbert
Mead said: "A
different Caesar crosses the Rubicon not only with each author but with each
generation." In the writing of The
Many-Splendored Society I have made several reformulations of the classics
of social science and humanities to fit into my schema, and to be more relevant
to the contemporary state of knowledge. The classics are here treated, not as
monuments, but as stepping stones.
The main division of social reality is not class, as Karl
Marxthought, but societal realms. They are six in number:
science, art, economy, religion, polity, and morality. They are the homes of
knowledge, beauty, wealth, sacredness, order, and virtue, all being cardinal values
of mankind.
Class is important enough as a division within the economy
that separates rich and poor, and all that this implies. However, not only
class, but other distinctions with roots outside the economy are important
independent stratifications. Consider, for example, scientific competence,
levels of artistic taste, high or low offices of political power, or measures
of religious sanctities, and, not to forget, distinctions in moral rectitude.
These stratifications are as real as that of economic class. Did Marx consider
them? Not explicitly in his writings, as far as I can tell. Robert K Merton notes that Friedrich
Engelsclaims in a letter to Josef Block that Marxwas fully aware of such distinctions – who
isn’t? – and that he included them in his notion of
class. If so, I would argue that they need to be separated according to the societal
realm to which they belong.
We reach a ‘many-splendored society’ if and when all stratifications
– competence, taste, class, sacredness, power, and rectitude – are given about
equal attention, sway, and honor, In such a setting, we would hear the voices
of money and political power, not as a soloists, but in a chorus of other
voices.
The counterpart to the class struggle in the latter type of society is stated in our
Proposition 10:4 on Monopolization of Cardinal Values
Proposition 10:4 recalled. Monopolization
of Cardinal Values: In any society, people who possess or
control a large amount of a cardinal value (knowledge, wealth, power, beauty,
sacredness, virtue) tend to act to preserve this situation.
This Proposition pinpoints a universal struggle to
monopolize any and all cardinal values of mankind, not just wealth.
The different societal realmshave become both units of analysis in social
science and co-authors of history. Max Weber
noted already in 1919 in a lecture on politics
as a vocation: “We are placed into various life-spheres, each of which are governed
by different laws”
Max Weber specified six societal spheres for advanced societies.
He called them "life orders" (Lebensordnungen).
They are the economic, political, religious, intellectual, erotic, and the
family order. A value sphere (Wertssphär) of
particular priorities matches each of these orders. The orders and spheres tend
to become relatively autonomous and develop their own structures with
considerable independence from one another. This Weber called Eigengesetzlichkeit
der Wertsphären, "the bounded autonomy of
spheres of value" in Swedberg’s translation. In
a couple of brilliant lectures on politics and science as professions, Weber
elucidated the competition of the life orders as a perpetual "struggle of
demons."
Scholars have argued about the number of life orders and
their value spheres, as does, for example,
The many insights of Mann, Waltzer,
Boltanski and Thévenot in
the spheres they define are remarkable. However, with the possible exception of
Mann, their spheres appear ad hoc and, in the main, they are related to a
contemporary phase of Western history. They do not relate to, nor constitute,
any systematic theory of society. The same can also be said about Max Weber’s
original delineations. Weber’s inclusion of the erotic value sphere in his
schema is unconnected to his somewhat related term ‘charisma’ in the same
publication – both include elements of infatuation with another person. It is
also unconnected to his previous taxonomy, the Kategorienlehre.
His biographer has linked it up to a particular period of his love life (Radkau 2009).
The Weberian familial life order
and erotic life order are part of the socially small world and are more based
on wants than aspirations. For the moment, we may leave out the two micro-sociological
spheres, the familial and erotic value spheres, from our list. The other life
orders – the economic, political, religious, intellectual spheres are
macro-concepts, and the values they comprise are aspirations unique to language-using
humankind.
More important, we need to add a moral realm to
Weber's list. A moral realm’s emotively grounded prescriptions cannot be
reduced to political or religious expressions. This sphere of morality may be
underdeveloped in the post-Athenian and post-Roman Western world, but is, nevertheless,
an independent area of life with Eigengesetzlichkeit. I do not think Weber
would have objections to the inclusion of a moral sphere. In several places in
his writings, he appears critical of a modern tendency to push moral statements
into the esthetic realm by saying that some-thing‚ is in ‘bad taste‛
rather than admitting that it ‘is morally deplorable.‛
The science that refuses to correct its classics is lost.
Classics are not eternal monuments but stepping stones to progress.
My second influential teacher of sociology after Torgny Segerstedt was Arnold M
Rose at the University of Minnesota. (Rose had been one of the two junior
authors of Gunnar Myrdal’s An American Dilemma.)
I was his research assistant in the
academic year 1950-51. He had his intellectual roots in “symbolic interactions”
as developed in the Chicago School of Sociology. He introduced me to teachings
of Ezra Park and Herbert Blumer. It was easy for me
to merge ideas I had learned from Segerstedt and from
the philosophy of language and linguistics with symbolic interactionism.
Park had studied in
Germany, and his doctoral dissertation in 1904 at Bonn University had the title
Masse und Publikum. A "mass," he said, is an agglomeration of people without contacts with
one another, but, which is exposed to a common source of information, e.g. the
same newspaper. A "public" is a gathering in which people talk to one another and become
aware of one another's viewpoints. The group, the public, the crowd was the beginning of a schema of different
forms of social interaction that came to characterize the most widely used
pre-war American text book in sociology
Updated
definitions of lasting forms of symbolic interaction can be distinguished, in
part, by the reciprocity of contacts and, in part, by the existence of a shared
source or sender of communication. The shared sender is a shared leadership
whenever the message includes explicit prescription about what to do, or implicit
prescriptions such as “Read this,” “Listen, ”Remember”.
Such a sender is what Segerstedt called “the source
of a norm.”
With
these two dimensions, reciprocity and leadership, we can define communication
structures. The combinations provide four types. All are clusters of
interconnected positions and roles.
|
|
|
|
|
Is there a common sender of communications? |
Yes |
No |
Yes |
No |
Are there mutual channels of contact? |
Yes |
Yes |
No |
No |
Structure of communications |
Organization |
Network |
Media |
Mass |
|
|
|
|
|
Participants |
Group |
Publics |
Audiences |
Atomized crowds |
Lifestyle |
Organization loyalists |
Gregarious networkers |
Media freaks |
Our
definitions provide different labels to the participants and to the structures
in which they are participating. Organizations thus have members. Networks, not
gaterings, house “publics.” Media have “audiences.” This streamlining of the terminology
implies that Park's original definitions and labels are changed. The
definitions of publics and audiences have been switched. The mass has a new definition.
How
can one justify such a switch? In part, it follows more recent speech habits. But
I justify it from a notion that “public opinion” is a spontaneous view in
publics as defined here. The corresponding spontaneous order in an economy is
the market prices, in science it is the current standpoint of science.
The
pollsters’ use of statistical samples of discrete individuals and demographic
units of analysis, rather than real communities, publics, networks, and groups,
was the most serious criticism leveled at the young polling enterprise in the
middle of the Twentieth Century. Public opinion, said the critics, evolves in
networks, sometimes with media input, but never in demographic categories of
unconnected individuals. This critique, most effectively advanced by Chicago
sociologist Herbert Blumer
Old-fashioned
network opinions recur as central in most modern theories of state, legitimacy,
and democracy. They appear under various tags, for example, “participatory democracy”
in several versions from de Tocqueville
For
all of these conceptions of democracy, the pollsters’ “public opinion by
demography” is largely ignorable, while “public opinion by networks” is highly
relevant. For the latter very sophisticated theories of democracy, the success
since the 1930s of George Gallup's and Elmo Roper’s public opinion by demography
appears as a problematic departure, with no or few arrivals at the current frontiers
of knowledge.
I
have changed Park’s terminology about “public” in my longstanding effort to
make Blumer’s public opinion as the relevant one to
contemporary democratic theory, not the public opinion from polls as we now
know them.
Organizations
are relatively stable interactions of social relations guided from a leadership
position. They are a kind of formalized resting-stages in the ever-going
processes of changing and preserving human encounters. Their opposite is interacting
with unorganized positions and social relations. This is what we call a network.
A
more advanced means of working with classifications is the so-called
"semiotic square," a diagram introduced below. Those who find such a
diagram incomprehensible can simply read on in the text to find the intended
categories. A semiotic square is actually more of a device for the author of a
schema of classification than for the reader of that classification.
Let
us use the device of a semiotic square
We
get two pay-offs. On the right side of the square is a well-known combination
that we recognize as mass media. On the left side, we obtain a seemingly
unfamiliar combination of a full-fledged organization and a full-fledged
network. We have no generally accepted word for this. However, we know some
illustrations, for example, the perfect firm (an organization) operating on the
perfect market (a network). We shall use as a generic term ‘netorg’ for this
phenomenon. All societal realms, not only in the economy, have netorgs.
The netorgs were not part of
Ezra Park’s scheme and the structuration of society taught by the pioneering
Chicago sociologists. It took us a semiotic square to bring them out in the
open in the study of social reality.
Given
two dimensions, leadership and boundary, we can devise a fourfold table, a construction
that is beloved by sociologists both in their theorizing and in their
statistical presentation of data. (To analyze data to separate effects of
different categories you may need eight- or sixteen-fold table.)
Common leadership |
|||
Yes |
No |
||
Outside boundary |
Yes |
Organizations |
Assemblies |
No |
Media |
Networks |
Three
of the categories are familiar from the Chicago School. A new category emerging
from this exercise is the ‘assembly,’ a structure called collegium in
the Roman Republic where it was recognized in the law as requiring three or
more members. They acted as a committee, no single person ruled them. Assemblies
are town meetings, legislatures, church concilia,
university faculties, alumni meetings, board meetings, family reunions, and
many other get-togethers of defined groups. They have rosters of members none
of whom rules over any others. They have no common leadership, only temporary
chairpersons.
Even the best informed scholars about the modern mode of research
in the context of applications admit that it has made “surprisingly small
contribution” to basic science
In 2011, the Swedish government gave the option to state universities
to abandon the rule by collegiate assembly and adopt the bureaucratic form
under a university president. We do not yet know the outcome of this
legislation.
Those universities which opt out from collegiate
self-government will, in their search for new knowledge, be like any research
institute in the private sector or in the central government. The executive
traditions in these sectors may certainly require that the employees become good
at producing research reports that meet the budgets of time and money. But on
the day of the deadline, they run the risk of discovering that the content of a
research report is dead dull. Several interesting insights or hunches, made in
passing by the research team, may lay by the wayside. They are wasted
hypotheses that did not happen to fit in the council-approved plan for the
project, or did not fit in the mindset of the boss of the research institute.
A theorist is more at
home in a collegiate structure than in a bureaucratic one.
The adjective "many-splendored" used in the title
of my series of books dates from the 1950s. It was invented and spelled
"many-splendoured" by Han Sugin, a Chinese-born author and physician writing in
English and French. One of her novels was turned into the 1955 film "Love
Is a Many-Splendored Thing," set in Hong Kong, starring Jennifer Jones and
William Holden. Their many-splendored love in the film struggles to overcome
the ingrown distrust of a racially and ethnically different couple and their
families. The most memorable scenes in the film are set on the high and windy
hills of Hong Kong where the lovers first meet.
Love is a many-splendored thing,
It's the April rose that only grows in the early
spring,
Love is nature's way of giving a reason to be living,
The golden crown that makes a man a
king.
The song won an Oscar but is since forgotten. I felt that
the adjective in its title, "many-splendored," deserved a longer
life. So I made it stand for a society with personal freedom and a differentiation
of six self-governing realms: economy, politics, science, art, religion, and
morality. To say it again, when these realms are joined in a voluntary
cooperation and no one rules totally over any other we have a many-splendored
society, in my view, a good one.
A last word. Do not compromise the
integrity of these realms by trying to totally merge them:
Proposition 10:14
recalled. Merged Societal Realms: (a)
Initially, the proponents of mergers between societal realms tend to become approvingly
evaluated in a society, particularly by its Takers. However, (b) any mergers of
full societal realms (including their cardinal values, stratifications,
organizations, networks, media, etc.) tend to create instable structures that
deteriorate over time. (c) The depth and the speed of this deterioration are inversely
related to the position of the merger on the Scale of Valence of Societal
Realms
In the long run, a full merger of societal realms results in
increasingly wobbly structures. For example, to merge the body politic and the
economy into a socialist society creates an unstable mixture. Likewise, we
sense instability coming when the polity merges with the realm of morality into
a Nordic-type welfare state.
Bally, Charles. La langage et
la vie. Geneva: Edition Atar, 1913.
Benhabib, Seyla, ed. Democracy and Difference.
Contesting the Boundaries of the Political. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press, 1996.
Blumer, Herbert. "Public Opinion and Public
Opinion Polling." The American Sociological Review, 1948.
Dahlberg, Caroline. Picturing the Public.
Advertising Self-Regulation in Sweden and the UK. Stockholm: Acta Universitates
Stockholmiensis, 2010.
de Tocqueville, Alexis. L'Ancien
Régime et la Révolution. (Several
English versions, latest is The Old Regime and the Revolution, 1998-2001,
edited and with an introduction and critical apparatus by François Furet and Françoise Mélonio and translated by Alan S. Kahan,
University of Chicago Press, Chicago, Il). 1856.
Gendell, Murray, and Hans L Zetterberg, . A
Sociological Almanac for the United States. Totowa, NJ: Bedminster Press,
1961.
Greimas, Agidas Julien. Sémantique
structurale. Recherche de méthode. Paris: Larousse, 1966.
Habermas, Jürgen. Strukturwandel
der Öffentlichkeit. Untersuchungen zu einer Kategorie der bürgerlichen
Gesellschaft. (Second edition).
Berlin and Neuwied: Luchterhand, 1965.
Himmelstrand, Ulf. Social Pressures, Attitudes and
Democratic Processes. Uppsala: Almqvist & Wiksell, 1960.
Lindskoug, Kerstin. Hänförelse
och förnuft. Om karisma och rationalitet i Max Webers sociologi. Lund: Dialog, 1979.
Mann, Michael. The Sources of Social Power: A History
of Power from the Beginning to 1760 A.D. Vol. I. Cambridge and New York:
Cambridge University Press, 1986.
Mead, George Herbert. Movements of Thought in the
Nineteenth Century. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1936.
Merton, Robert K. "Insiders and Outsiders: A
Chapter in the Sociology of Knowledge." 78 (1972): 9-47.
Morris, Charles William. Signs, Language and
Behavior. New York, NY: Prentice Hall, 1946.
Nowotny, Helga, Peter Scott, and Michael Gibbons. Re-Thinking
Science. Knowledge and the Public in an Age of Uncertainty. Cambridge, UK:
Polity Press, 2001.
Park, Robert E, and Ernst W. Burgess. Introduction
to the Science of Sociology. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press,
1924.
Rawls, John. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press, 1971.
Saussure, Ferdinand de. Cours
de linguistique générale. (Translated
as Course in General Linguistics, 1959, Philosophical Library, New York).
Edited by Charles Bally. Paris, 1916/1959.
Scaff, Lawrence A. Fleeing the Iron Cage.
Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1989.
Segerstedt, Torgny. Ordens
makt. Stockholm: Natur & Kultur, 1944.
—. Social Control as
a Sociological Concept. Uppsala: Lundequistska, 1948.
—. Verklighet och
värde. Lund: Gleerup, 1938.
Stevenson, Charles L. Ethics and Language. New
Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1944.
Swedberg, Richard. The Max Weber Dictionary. Key
Words and Central Concepts. With the assistance of Ola Agevall. Stanford,
CA: Stanford University press, 2005.
van Doren, Mark. The Happy Critic and Other Essays
. New York: Hill & Wang, 1961.
Weber, Max. From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology.
Introduction by Hans H. Gerth and C. Wright Mills. Edited by H.H. Gerth,
& C. Wright Mills. Translated by H.H. Gerth, & C. Wright Mills. New
York: Oxford University Press, 1946.
—. From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology.
Introduction by Hans H. Gerth and C. Wright Mills. Édité par H.H. Gerth,
& C. Wright Mills. Traduit par H.H. Gerth, & C. Wright Mills. New
York: Oxford University Press, 1946.
—. Gesammelte
Aufsätze zur Wissenschaftslehre. Tübingen: J. C. B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck),
1922.
—. Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. (Translated
1968 by Guenter Roth and Claus Wittich as Economy and Society. New York:
Bedminster Press). Tübingen: J. C. B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck), 1922/1968.
Zetterberg, Hans L. A Semantic Role Theory.
MA-thesis, Minneapolis, Minnesota: University of Minnesota, 1951.
—. Social Theory and Social Practice. New
York: Bedminster Press, 1962.
--. "Sociology." In Sources
of Information in the Social Sciences, edited by Carl H White, 183-209.
Totowa, NJ: Bedminster Press, 1965.
—. The Many-Splendored Society: An Edifice of
Symbols. Vol. 2. Scott Valley CA and Charleston NC: POD, CreateSpace,
2010, 2nd enlarged ed. 2011.
—. The Many-Splendored Society: Fuelled by
Symbols. Vol. 3. Scotts Valley CA and Charleston SC: POD, CreateSpace,
2010, 2nd ed. 2011.
—. The Many-Splendored Society: Surrounded by
Symbols. Vol. 1. Scotts Valley CA and Charleston NC: POD, CreateSpace,
2009, 2nd ed. 2011.
[1] I did
developed two small objections to Morris. His fourth category, the systemic use
of language, is not separate from the three others. Nothing can be systemic
that is not originally informative, and/or valuative,
and/or incitive. The systemic is an attribute of the
other three basic usages of communication. It is the attribute of rationalism.
The second objection is the above Bally observation; Morris immediately
obfuscated his big discovery by trying to cross-classify his universal uses of
language with the structure of the school grammar of language